Analysis Five Forces Of Framework

Page 1

This paper seeks to contribute thinking on how the intellectual foundations of

antitrust might be updated, based on a large body of theoretical and empirical research on

company strategy, competition, and economic development. The aim is to outline a new

direction for antitrust that can be incorporated into government policy and legal practice

and pursued in litigation and legislation, both in the United States and internationally.

This new thinking sets forth as the basic goal of antitrust policy, and

employs tools like industry structure analysis and locational analysis to evaluate potential

impacts on competition. While there appears to be broad consensus on how to deal with

much anticompetitive behavior such as deceptive practices and cartel formation, the

current fault line in antitrust is the treatment of mergers. This paper therefore focuses on

the evaluation of mergers, though the same framework can be applied to evaluating joint

ventures, other combinations, and other competitive practices. Finally, it should be noted

that this paper is concerned principally with the content of antitrust, not the many

important issues involved in structuring antitrust agencies and designing processes of

enforcement.

Section II argues that the true benefits of healthy competition are not fully articulated

in much antitrust analysis. By linking competition to a nation’s standard of living

through productivity growth, it becomes apparent that far more is at stake in protecting

competition than short-term consumer welfare defined by price-cost margins. Empirical

evidence is provided to highlight the importance of protecting the vitality of competition.

Furthermore, it is argued that local competition within a nation is particularly crucial for

competitiveness, even in the era of globalization.

Section III proposes that productivity growth become the new standard for antitrust,

and reassesses the hierarchy of antitrust goals accordingly.

Since healthy competition

will foster productivity growth, antitrust must be equipped with adequate tools and

frameworks for evaluating the health of competition. Yet frameworks broader than

current practices resting in relevant market definitions and ability to elevate price above

cost are required. So called “five forces” analysis is offered as a broader tool for

evaluating overall industry competition, while the diamond framework for locational

competitiveness is offered for evaluating the health of local competition.

In Section IV, we turn to the analysis of mergers, outlining a three-level merger

evaluation process that incorporates the productivity growth standard and the tools for

evaluating the health of competition mentioned above. Section V offers a short case

study of a merger evaluation, using the new procedure.

Finally, Section VI addresses

some recent issues more specific to U. S. antitrust policy.

The essential role of competition and antitrust policy in competitiveness is evident in

recent research on industry competition and economic development. My conviction from

working both with companies and public policymakers in many countries is that open

competition, stimulated by strict antitrust enforcement, is essential not only to national

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 2

prosperity, but to the health of companies themselves. Yet antitrust seems to be drifting.

Antitrust policy is being challenged by skeptics who are mounting attacks on the need for

antitrust under the guise of globalization or the requirements of the “new economy.”

Also, the theoretical and empirical literature on competition has moved beyond seller

concentration, price-cost margins, and other ideas central to current enforcement. 1

It is an important moment to reinvigorate antitrust. Not to say that antitrust

enforcement has been lax, nor that skilled practitioners have not been able to apply the

law with great sophistication. However, recent court rulings and public debate suggest

that the foundations of antitrust theory and practice are wearing thin. The goals of

antitrust and its link to society’s goals are often not convincingly articulated. The

benefits of competition that underpin antitrust have not been made clear, and the tools for

measuring impacts on competition are frequently controversial.

Too often the discussion

between business and government in antitrust proceedings concerns arcane matters such

as HHI that erodes the legitimacy of antitrust with the private sector. By relying too

heavily on narrowly conceived consumer welfare theory, antitrust analysis may be

overlooking some of the most important benefits of competition for society. Antitrust is

not living up to its full promise in deterring behavior that is not in society’s interest.

My aim here is not to offer a comprehensive treatise, settle all of the issues raised, nor

do justice to the scholarly or practitioner literature. Instead, the intention is to stimulate

further dialogue and analysis.

1 See Sections II and III.

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 3

II. COMPETITION, COMPETITIVENESS, AND STANDARD OF

LIVING: THE ROLE OF ANTITRUST

II. 1. Competition, productivity growth, and standard of living

The stated role of antitrust policy is to promote and protect competition in the name

of consumer welfare. Yet the rationale is frequently unclear, misunderstood, or too

narrow in scope. While protecting short-run consumer welfare measured by price-cost

margins is undeniably important, the benefits of healthy competition are in fact broader

and more essential to consumers and to society.

The fundamental benefit of competition

is to drive productivity growth through innovation, where innovation is defined broadly

to include not only products, but also processes and methods of management.

Productivity growth is central because it is the single most important determinant of longterm

consumer welfare and a nation’s standard of living.

The underpinnings of economic prosperity are becoming better understood as a result

of continuing research. While sound macroeconomic policies and stable political and

legal institutions represent important preconditions for prosperity and competitiveness,

they are necessary but not sufficient conditions for a prosperous economy. Prosperity is

actually generated at the microeconomic level – in the ability of firms to create valuable

goods and services productively that will support high wages and high returns to capital. 2

The goal of economic development is to achieve long term, sustainable improvement

in a nation’s standard of living, which can be approximated by per capita national income

(GDP per capita).

3 Per capita income is determined by the productivity of a nation’s

economy, where productivity is defined as the total value of the goods and services

(products) produced per unit of the nation’s human, capital and physical resources. A

nation’s overall productivity is composed of the productivity of its firms, both those

involved in traded industries and those involved in purely local commerce. The crucial

issue, then, is how to create the conditions for rapid and sustained productivity growth in

a nation’s firms.

Since the seminal contributions of Schumpeter (1943), Solow (1956) and Abramovitz

(1956), it is widely understood that the only means of achieving sustained productivity

growth in an economy is through innovation. 4 Innovation provides products and services

2 M.

E. Porter, “The Microeconomic Foundations of Economic Development,” in The Global

Competitiveness Report 1998, 38 (Geneva: World Economic Forum, 1998). See also M. E.

Porter,

“Attitudes, Values, Beliefs, and the Microeconomics of Prosperity,” in Culture Matters: How Values

Shape Human Progress (L. E. Harrison & S. P. Huntington eds. , 2000).

3 While income is the best available measure, other things contribute to national standard of living

besides wages and returns to capital, such as the quality of health care, the absence of extreme income

inequality, and environmental quality.

4 J. Schumpeter, Capitalism, Socialism, and Democracy (2 d ed. 1943); R.

Solow, “Technical Change

and the Aggregate Production Function,” 39 Review of Economics and Statistics 312 (1957); R. Solow,

“A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Growth,” 70 Quarterly Journal of Economics 65 (1956);

(continue)

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 4

of ever-increasing consumer value, as well as ways of producing products more

efficiently, both of which contribute directly to productivity.

Innovation, in this broad sense, is driven by competition. While technological

innovation is the result of a variety of factors, there is no doubt that healthy competition

is an essential part. One need only review the dismal innovation record of countries

lacking strong competition to be convinced of this fact.

Vigorous competition in a

supportive business environment is the only path to sustained productivity growth, and

therefore to long term economic vitality.

Productivity growth, then, is the missing, unstated link between competition and

national standard of living. This provides the soundest explanation for why antitrust must

protect competition: it is the key to a nation’s economic prosperity. Productivity growth

thinking also makes it clear that the focus of antitrust thinking should be on the long-term

trajectory of product value and price, not just current consumer welfare measured by

short-run prices. The following sections outline how the central role of productivity in

development and societal welfare can be applied to antitrust and competition policy.

II.

2. Importance of Industry Competition: empirical evidence

Recent empirical findings verify the importance of competition to raising and

maintaining standard of living. This evidence squares well with my own experience.

Competition really matters, in the new economy and the old economy, and in all types of

countries.

One body of empirical evidence comes from The Global Competitiveness Report

2000, an annual study of competitiveness in 58 countries including all the OECD

countries as well as many developing countries. 5 Data from the report are drawn from a

survey of more than 4, 000 corporate and other leaders, including a representative sample

from each country.

The survey is qualitative, but represents a large body of expert

opinion on important dimensions of economic policy, for which there are no quantitative

measures.

Figure 1 reproduces some of the statistical findings from the Report. For all three

years in which this analysis has been conducted, the effectiveness of antitrust policy 6

proves to be one of the variables with the strongest positive association with the variation

in GDP per capita across countries. This holds even in the subsample of developing

(continued)

M.

Abramowitz, “Resource and Output Trends in the United States since 1870,” 46 American

Economic Review 5 (1956).

5 M. E. Porter, “The Current Competitiveness Index: Measuring the Economic Foundations of

Prosperity,” in The Global Competitiveness Report 2000 (Geneva: World Economic Forum, 2000).

6 In id. at 312, the effectiveness of antitrust policy was measured in a survey by responses to question

10.

14, “The anti-monopoly policy effectively promotes competition,” using a scale from 1-7, “strongly

disagree” to “strongly agree.”

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 5

economies, an indication that antitrust is also important for poor countries, rather than

just a luxury needed only in wealthy ones. The report also includes a survey question

about the intensity of local competition. While the question is imperfect because of

possible ambiguities in its interpretation by respondents, it also has a highly significant

positive association with GDP per capita.

Figure 1 Competition and Prosperity: Findings from The Global Competitiveness

Report

Regression

Dependent Variable: 1994 – 99 GDP per capita growth

Significance Adj R 2

Measure of National Business at 95% level

Environment

Intensity of local competition at 95% level. 255

Effectiveness of Antitrust policy at 95% level.

117

Regression

Dependent Variable: 1994 – 99 GDP per capita growth

Significance Adj R 2

Measure of National Business at 95% level

Environment

Intensity of local competition at 95% level. 255

Effectiveness of Antitrust policy at 95% level. 117

Regression

Dependent Variable: 1999 GDP per capita

Significance Adj R 2

Measure of National Business at 95% level

Environment

Effectiveness of antitrust policy at 95% level. 700

Intensity of local competition at 95% level.

320

Regression

Dependent Variable: 1999 GDP per capita

Significance Adj R 2

Measure of National Business at 95% level

Environment

Effectiveness of antitrust policy at 95% level. 700

Intensity of local competition at 95% level. 320

.”.. countries where the intensity of competition is rising

showed by far the greatest improvement in GDP per capita.”

Source: M. E. Porter, “The Current Competitiveness Index: Measuring the Microeconomic Foundations of

Prosperity”, in The Global Competitiveness Report 2000 (Geneva: World Economic Forum, 2000).

Turning to analysis of the rate of growth in GDP per capita, the effectiveness of

antitrust policy and the intensity of competition are again highly significant variables and

contribute substantially to explained variance. Note that the proportion of variance in

GDP per capita growth rate that can be explained is inherently less than for the level of

GDP, because growth in GDP is more sensitive to a wide variety of shocks and shortterm

macroeconomic influences. We find that the competition / antitrust policy measures

are as or more associated with prosperity as transportation infrastructure, telecom

infrastructure, IT readiness, and the like. In a first difference analysis, countries where

the intensity of competition is rising showed registered the greatest improvement in GDP

per capita. All these findings are consistent: competition and a vigorous antitrust policy

are strongly associated with national prosperity.

This research provides some positive evidence of the importance of strong antitrust

for prosperity. There is also ample negative evidence to be cited. For example, Japan is

a country with a history of weak antitrust enforcement, legal cartels, and extensive

government-sponsored collaborative research projects among companies. During the

height of the Japanese economic miracle, the case of Japan was a principal argument

advanced in the United States for weakening antitrust law – for example, in allowing

potentially anticompetitive collaborative activity. 7

7 M. E.

Porter, H. Takeuchi & M. Sakakibara, Can Japan Compete? (2000).

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 6

Yet one of the major findings of a recent book is the steep price that Japan has paid

for a lax antitrust policy. 8 Our research revealed that weak antitrust enforcement did not

explain Japanese competitiveness, but was in fact an explanation for why certain

industries in Japan were uncompetitive. Industries where competition was limited by

Japanese government policy were uncompetitive.

We also collected data on all the legal

cartels in post-World War II Japan, and found that the industries in which cartels

occurred were, with few exceptions, uncompetitive. We also collected data on all

government-sponsored cooperative research projects, which involved several if not most

industry competitors. We found that those industries in which cooperative research

projects occurred were no more likely than the average industry to be competitive, and

many cooperative research projects actually worked against industry competitiveness.

There have been many collaborative projects in the West involving multiple industry

competitors growing out of the efforts to emulate the Japanese case, such as the electric

vehicle project. With few if any exceptions, these have proven disappointing.

The

notion that Japan was competitive because of weak antitrust is resoundingly rejected.

Figure 2 highlights some additional data drawn from our study of Japan. We

explored the relationship between the intensity of domestic competition and world export

share in a broad sample of Japanese industries. All of the industries considered were

global in scope.

Industries able to command a high world export share were decreed to

be highly productive.

Instead of relying on market structure measures such as seller concentration to proxy

the intensity of competition, we used the extent of fluctuations in domestic market share

among leading firms over an 18-year period. The fluctuation in market share among

leading competitors – controlling for outside shocks – provides a direct and far more

compelling indication of the intensity of competition. 9 We found that domestic market

share variability was by far the most powerful influence on Japanese world export share,

dominating conventional measures of comparative advantage such as skilled labor

intensity and capital intensity. The intensity of competition at home, then, was the

strongest influence on Japanese competitiveness abroad.

These statistical findings are

consistent with hundreds of industry case studies that have been conducted on the

determinants of competitiveness at the country level, as well as research on national and

regional economic development. 10

Interestingly, we found that seller concentration had no significant relationship with

Japanese world export share. 11 Nor was it significantly correlated with the extent of

8 Id. See also M. Sakakibara & M. E.

Porter, “Competing at Home to Win Abroad: Evidence from

Japanese Industry,” 83 Review of Economics and Statistics 310 (2001).

9 See generally R. Caves & M. Porter, “Market Structure, Oligopoly, and Stability of Market Shares,” 26

Journal of Industrial Economics 289 (1978). For a detailed application to Japan, including definitions,

sources of data, cause and effect issues, see Sakakibara & Porter, supra note 8.

10 See, e.

g. , “Clusters and Competition: New agendas for Companies, Governments, and Institutions” in

M. E. Porter, On Competition (1998), which contains an extensive bibliography.

11 Sakakibara & Porter, supra note 8.

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 7

domestic market share fluctuations.

These results are consistent with other research

which raises doubts about the use of seller concentration as a proxy for the vitality of

competition. 12

Figure 2 Competition and International Competitiveness: Evidence from Japanese

Industry

Competitiveness Competitiveness

Local Competition Local Competition

o Measured by World Export Share

o Measured by Fluctuations in

Domestic Market Share

Sakakibara/Porter:

“We find a positive and highly

significant relationship between the

extent of market share fluctuations [a

measure of local rivalry] and trade

performance

Contrary to some popular views, our

results suggest that Japanese

competitiveness is associated with

home market competition, not

collusion, cartels, or government

intervention that stabilize it.”

Source: M. Sakakibara & M. E. Porter, “Competing at Home to Win Abroad: Evidence from Japanese

Industry”, 83 Review of Economics and Statistics 310, 318, 319 (May 2001).

II.

3. Importance of Local Competition 13: Externalities, cluster theory, and the link

between clusters and innovation

The Japanese research and other evidence suggest that, contrary to popular belief,

local competition matters in global industries. Even where firms compete across borders,

the configuration of locally based competitors and the vitality of competition in the local

market are crucial to productivity and competitiveness. Local competition creates

numerous positive externalities for industries and industry clusters, thus explaining its

significant impact on firm competitiveness.

Many industries can be considered global in competitive scope, which is often taken

to imply that a firm’s location is of no importance to the health of competition.

Yet the

actual distribution of firms belies this view. We observe a strong tendency for successful

12 See, e. g. , K. Ewing, “The Soft Underbelly of Antitrust,” Antitrust Report, Sept. 1999 at 2; B.

Harris &

D. Smith, “The Merger Guidelines v. Economics: A Survey of Economic Studies,” Antitrust Report,

Sept. 1999 at 23; C. Weller, “An Evolution of the Merger-JV Guidelines: The Productivity Paradigm

As A Positive Antitrust Policy for Competitiveness and Prosperity,” American Bar Association,

Perspectives of the Task Force on Fundamental Theory (forthcoming, 2001).

13 It should be noted that the term local can apply to geographic areas ranging from a small county to a

group of neighboring countries.

The relevant economic area depends on geographic distance and the

scope of local externalities.

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 8

firms in a particular industry to cluster in particular countries, often along with firms in

related industries. The schematic map of the U. S. clusters in figure 3 shows that

geographic clustering can occur even in sub-national regions within countries. This

ubiquitous phenomenon reveals powerful insights into the role of location in healthy

competition.

Figure 3 Selected Regional Clusters of Competitive U. S. Industries

Omaha

Telemarketing

Hotel Reservations

Credit Card Processing

Wisconsin / Iowa / Illinois

Agricultural Equipment

Detroit

Auto

Equipment

and Parts

Rochester

Imaging

Equipment

Western Massachusetts

Polymers

Boston

Mutual Funds

Biotechnology

Software and

Networking

Venture

Capital

Hartford

Insurance

Providence

Jewelry

Marine Equipment

New York City

Financial Services

Advertising

Publishing

Multimedia

Pennsylvania / New Jersey

Pharmaceuticals

North Carolina

Household Furniture

Synthetic Fibers

Hosiery

Dalton, Georgia

Carpets

South Florida

Health Technology

Computers

Nashville /

Louisville

Hospital

Management

Baton Rouge /

New Orleans

Specialty Foods

Southeast Texas

/ Louisiana

Chemicals

Dallas

Real Estate

Development

Wichita

Light Aircraft

Farm Equipment

Los Angeles Area

Defense Aerospace

Entertainment

Silicon Valley

Microelectronics

Biotechnology

Venture Capital

Cleveland / Louisville

Paints & Coatings

Pittsburgh

Advanced Materials

Energy

West Michigan

Office and Institutional

Furniture

Michigan

Clocks

Carlsbad

Golf Equipment

Minneapolis

Cardio-vascular

Equipment

and Services

Warsaw, Indiana

Orthopedic Devices

Colorado

Computer Integrated Systems / Programming

Engineering Services

Mining / Oil and Gas Exploration

Phoenix

Helicopters

Semiconductors

Electronic Testing Labs

Optics

Las Vegas

Amusement /

Casinos

Small Airlines

Oregon

Electrical Measuring

Equipment

Woodworking Equipment

Logging / Lumber

Supplies

Seattle

Aircraft Equipment and Design

Boat and Ship Building

Metal Fabrication

Boise

Sawmills

Farm Machinery

Firms cluster in particular locations not because of traditional comparative advantages

stemming from natural resources or pools of cheap labor. Rather, they obtain competitive

advantages by locating in areas benefiting from the strong presence of other firms in the

industry, firms in related industries, and the presence of specialized inputs, information,

and institutions.

The explanation for geographic clustering is that local competition

provides an exceptional stimulus to productivity growth that is extremely valuable to

firms. The two major contributions of local competition are:

1. Incentive and Informational Benefits: The immediate presence of a rival

stimulates greater comparison, improvement, and upgrading versus competing

with a firm in a foreign country. Companies that compete at home are better

prepared to compete with foreign rivals abroad.

2. Positive Externalities: Geographic proximity of rivals generates otherwise

unattainable positive externalities, such as a specialized labor pools,

knowledge spillovers, specialized supplier formation, etc.

discussed below.

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 9

The Positive Externalities of Local Rivalry. Competition creates positive externalities for

the local business environment that boost productivity for the entire industry, and often

for related and supporting industries in the same location as well. A group of competing

local rivals tends to spawn a base of local suppliers and providers of specialized support

services.

This boosts productivity by reducing transactions costs, facilitating the

exchange of information, increasing flexibility, and speeding innovation. Local rivalry

also works to increase the local availability of specialized skills, infrastructure, scientific

and technical resources, and other assets and institutions that boost productivity and raise

the rate of productivity growth. As these externalities deepen, they can foster new entry

and spinoffs, coming full circle to reinforce local rivalry. Such externalities are what

give rise to what I term clusters, or geographic concentrations of interconnected

companies and institutions in a particular field.

California wine provides a good example of a cluster (see figure 4). There are

hundreds of wineries in California, but also thousands of independent growers of grapes.

All the inputs, production equipment, and services required to grow grapes and produce

wine are available locally. Local universities and other institutions provide ample skilled

labor and technological information. As a result, the productivity of California as a wine producing

region in terms of yield per acre appears to be the highest in the world, and

firms command high prices per bottle for their premium-quality products. The rate of

productivity growth has been rapid, as California wine companies upgraded from jug

wine to super premium segments.

Figure 4 The California Wine Cluster

Educational, Research, & Trade

Organizations (e. g.

Wine Institute,

UC Davis, Culinary Institutes)

Educational, Research, & Trade

Organizations (e. g. Wine Institute,

UC Davis, Culinary Institutes)

Growers/Vineyards Growers/Vineyards Wineries/Processing

Facilities

Wineries/Processing

Facilities

Grapestock Grapestock

Fertilizer, Pesticides,

Herbicides

Fertilizer, Pesticides,

Herbicides

Grape Harvesting

Equipment

Grape Harvesting

Equipment

Irrigation Technology Irrigation Technology

Winemaking

Equipment

Winemaking

Equipment

Barrels Barrels

Labels Labels

Bottles Bottles

Caps and Corks Caps and Corks

Public Relations and

Advertising

Public Relations and

Advertising

Specialized Publications

(e. g. , Wine Spectator,

Trade Journal)

Specialized Publications

(e. g.

, Wine Spectator,

Trade Journal)

Food Cluster Food Cluster

Tourism Cluster Tourism Cluster California

Agricultural Cluster

California

Agricultural Cluster

State Government Agencies

(e. g. , Select Committee on Wine

Production and Economy)

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 10

Source: M. E. Porter, On Competition (1998), at ch.

7.

Other well-known examples of U. S. clusters include the Silicon Valley IT cluster, the

Houston oil and gas cluster, and the Boston area biopharmaceuticals and mutual fund

clusters.

The Global Competitiveness Report includes measures of the quality and quantity of

local suppliers and, in the 2000 report the extent of clusters in a national economy. All

three variables have a strong positive association with GDP per capita.

Taking into account the essential benefits of local competition leads to the conclusion

that antitrust analysis should weigh not just the generalized benefits of rivalry for

productivity growth but also the systemic benefits of local rivalry. When local rivalry is

muted, a nation pays a double price. Not only will companies face less pressure to be

productive, but the business environment for all local companies in the industry, their

suppliers, and firms in related industries will become less productive. This demonstrates

in particular the danger in arguments about the creation of “national champions” in an

industry in the home country in order to gain the scale to compete internationally. Unless

a firm is forced to compete at home, it will usually quickly lose its competitiveness

abroad. Local competition matters for productivity and productivity growth, even in

industries whose geographic scope is global.

14

Note that no mention has been made of the ownership of the locally based firms.

This is because ownership has much less importance for externalities than the nature of

the activities undertaken in a given location. All firms in a given location must be

considered part of the cluster, not merely the domestic ones. Special weight for

competition derives from locally based entities that have significant development,

production, and other activities located in a nation. These offer far greater potential for

externalities than does competition from imports.

Trade is not a full substitute for local

competition.

14 See, e. g. , The Global Competitiveness Report 1998 (various authors) (Geneva: World Economic

Forum, 1998); The Global Competitiveness Report 1999 (various authors) (Geneva: World Economic

Forum, 1999); The Global Competitiveness Report 2000 (various authors) (Geneva: World Economic

Forum, 2000).

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 11

III – THE GOALS AND TOOLS OF ANTITRUST POLICY

III.

1. New Standard for Antitrust: Productivity Growth

Since the role of competition is to increase a nation’s standard of living and long-term

consumer welfare via rising productivity growth, the new standard for antitrust should be

productivity growth, rather than price / cost margins or profitability. All combinations or

practices scrutinized in antitrust should be subjected to the following question: how will

they affect productivity growth? If a merger, joint venture, or other arrangement will

significantly enhance productivity growth, it is probably good for society and for

consumers (as well as the firms involved). Transactions with dubious benefits for

productivity growth, or those that offer only a one-time productivity benefit, are likely to

be net negatives for society if they pose any risk to the overall health of competition.

This is because competition is a primary determinant of future long-term productivity

growth.

How would the productivity growth standard affect antitrust? The current explicit and

implicit goals of U. S. antitrust policy fall roughly into the following hierarchy (see figure

5). Drawing on Welfare theory, the primary focus in U. S.

antitrust for the last twenty

years has been on limiting price / cost margins or firm profitability (allocative inefficiency)

as the most important outcome for consumers. Market power is seen as giving firms the

ability to elevate prices and sustain high margins. Hence, limiting market power is the

major focus of attention.

Figure 5 Goals of Antitrust Policy

Traditional View Alternative View

Profitability / Price-Cost Margins

(allocative efficiency)

Cost reduction

(static efficiency)

Cost

(static efficiency)

Innovation

(dynamic efficiency)

Innovation

(dynamic efficiency)

Value improvement

(static productivity)

Profitability / Price-cost margin

standard

Productivity growth standard

Profitability / Price-Cost Margins

(allocative efficiency)

Second in importance in antitrust evaluations has been cost or technical efficiency.

The efficiency justification can be used to offset a finding of market power to elevate

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 12

margins. At the bottom of the current hierarchy is innovative ness, or the rate of dynamic

improvement.

The effect of mergers or competitive practices on the overall rate of

innovation is usually only paid lip service.

If these three goals are tested against the productivity growth standard, it becomes

clear that the traditional hierarchy of goals should be reversed.

Because of its direct effect on productivity growth, the most important goal for

society is a healthy process of dynamic improvement, which requires innovations in

products, processes, or ways of managing. If the rate of dynamic improvement is

healthy, over time this dominates static technical and allocative efficiency concerns. For

example, a faster rate of innovation in new approaches overwhelms static economies of

scale in existing approaches, particularly in an age where knowledge-based competition

is the rule.

A productivity growth standard suggests that technical (static) efficiency should be

the second most important goal, but that it must be assessed with more subtlety.

While

antitrust analysis tends to focus on cost justifications, equal attention should be paid to

product or service value. Roughly speaking, productivity is price times quantity divided

by the quantity of labor or capital involved. It can be divided into two distinct

components: the prices that products command in the marketplace (which reflect value)

and the efficiency with which a unit of product can be produced. Thus, productivity is

enhanced not just by efficiency improvements, but also by improvements in product

quality, features, and services. Product variety is also an essential component of value,

giving customers more choices to better meet their particular needs.

High-value products provide the consumer with superior performance and features,

and therefore justify higher prices.

With a focus on price / cost margins, however, high

prices are often seen as inherently undesirable for consumers. Higher prices should be a

danger sign in antitrust analysis only if they are not justified by rising customer value.

Limiting short-term price / cost margins or profitability is a dubious goal for antitrust.

Firm profitability is a good thing if it reflects truly superior products or significant

advantages in process technology or operating efficiency. It is a bad thing if it occurs in

the absence of a healthy rate of dynamic improvement. In a typical industry, average

price-cost margins and profitability will vary significantly among competitors, reflecting

varying levels of fundamental competitiveness.

Short-term consumer welfare measured by price, then, is a dubious goal on two

levels. First, it fails to measure true consumer welfare by ignoring product value.

Second, we care much more about the long-term trajectory of value, prices, and costs

than we do about consumer welfare in the short run or immediately after a merger.

Moreover, a productivity growth standard is entirely consistent with the language of the

main antitrust laws.

Benefits of a Productivity Growth Standard. Why is the productivity growth standard

different and important for antitrust? First, it is a positive standard that relates directly to

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 13

competitiveness, a nation’s standard of living, and long-term consumer value, while

price / cost margins and technical efficiency are theoretically suspect. Productivity growth

is also more understandable and palatable to managers. Imagine how much more

constructive it would be for corporations and their attorneys to debate whether a merger

will boost productivity growth rather than continuing to debate the size of HHI.

Second, a productivity growth standard would shift antitrust away from a narrow

focus on static, short-term consumer welfare to a dynamic and more all-encompassing

view of competition and its benefits to consumers, firms, and society as whole. Defining

the goal of antitrust in terms of price / cost margins and profitability creates a zero-sum

game between firms and consumers.

If consumers are to benefit from lower prices, firms

must earn lower profits. In contrast, a productivity growth standard raises no inevitable

trade-off. If productivity is growing, consumers can enjoy better products and / or lower

prices, companies can earn attractive returns on capital, and workers can enjoy rising

wages. A productivity growth standard, then, unites the perspectives of consumers,

workers, and companies. It embodies a positive sum rather than a zero-sum view of

competition. An approach to competition based on productivity growth will lead to

outcomes that benefit consumers far more than a shortsighted concern with static

profitability.

Finally, productivity growth addresses the reality of high-technology industries and

the so-called new economy by highlighting the fundamental importance of innovation.

While there are few true conceptual differences between the “new” and “old” economies,

the apparent mismatch between the static focus of antitrust and the rapid change in

technology-intensive industries has undermined antitrust’s legitimacy. Since innovation

is the basic driver of productivity growth, promoting and protecting it should be central.

III. 2. Analysis of competition

How would the productivity standard be applied in practice? The best way to attain

maximal productivity growth in an industry is to ensure that industry competition is

healthy, since competition determines long-term productivity growth.

It is possible to

measure past productivity growth in various ways, and we advocate that this become part

of antitrust analysis. However, predicting future productivity growth is more difficult.

Hence, there is a need for tools to assess the likely future health of competition, since this

will be the single most important factor in whether future gains in productivity will reach

their potential.

III.

2. 1. Measuring the health of industry competition: Five Forces Analysis

To measure the health of competition in practice, we agree with those who believe

that seller concentration, the number of firms in a market, and profitability are not very

good indicators. 15 They capture only part of a complex phenomenon and divert analyses

15 See, e. g. , Ewing, supra note 12; Harris & Smith, supra note 12; Weller, supra note 12.

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 14

of competition to much less productive debates over where to draw relevant market

boundaries. Instead, a broader approach is necessary. One such approach with

acceptance in business practice is the “five forces” analysis of the intensity of

competition.

The Five Forces Model.

16 The five forces model is a dynamic approach to analyzing

industry structure, based on five competitive forces acting in an industry or sub-industry:

threat of entry, threat of substitution, bargaining power of buyers, bargaining power of

suppliers, and rivalry among current competitors. 17

This approach, with roots in industrial economics but moving beyond its narrower

interpretations, posits that competition in an industry is broader than price, and includes

product features, services, and processes. Competition is also seen as driven by many

influences. The five forces framework seeks to encompass all the important dimensions

of competition (see figure 6). It embodies the notion that competition is much broader

than just rivalry, where seller concentration (HHI) analysis is focused. Any of the five

forces can be significant in determining the health of competition, depending on the

particular industry.

For example, the power of customers to push down price or pressure

improvements in service can be just as important to productivity growth as the number

and size distribution of competitors in the market. 18

Five forces theory also argues that for any one of the competitive forces, the causes of

competitive intensity are multidimensional. In assessing the intensity of rivalry, for

example, seller concentration does have a role, although our interpretation would focus

more on the balance of competitors (the more balanced, the more rivalry). But the

intensity of rivalry also depends on a series of other dimensions, including, for example,

the industry cost structure. Where variable costs are low, strong pressures are created to

cut price in order to contribute to fixed cost. With such a cost structure, even a

concentrated industry can exhibit strong rivalry.

Switching costs are another important

influence on rivalry. Where it is easy for customers to shift from one supplier to another,

the effect of concentration is mitigated.

The five forces methodology involves analysis on an industry-by-industry basis, and

does not rest on the determination of the relevant market. Every industry is different,

16 There is an extensive literature on five forces analysis that is beyond the scope of this article to

summarize here. The early references are M. E.

Porter, Inter brand Choice, Strategy, and Bilateral

Market Power (1976); M. E. Porter, Competitive Strategy: Techniques for Analyzing Industries and

Competitors (1980).

17 Brandenburger and Nalebuff have appropriately stressed the role of complementary products in

competition, and some have suggested complementary products as a sixth force (A. Brandenburger &

B.

Nalebuff, Co-o petition, (1996) ). However, complementary products do not directly influence the

health of competition, but affect it indirectly through the influence of complements on the five forces.

The presence of a complementary product is neither good nor bad for competition per se. It depends

on how the complement influences, for example, barriers to entry or the power of the customer.

18 There is substantial empirical support for the importance of this broader set of industry attributes for

competition.

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 15

both in terms of the relative influence of the forces and the array of drivers of each force.

This approach, which squares with actual industry competition, has been well accepted in

corporate practice and in management consulting firms to assess the nature of industry

competition.

Figure 6 Assessing the Health of Competition: Five Forces Framework

Threat of Substitute

Products or

Services

Threat of New

Entrants

Rivalry Among

Existing

Competitors

Bargaining Power

of Suppliers

Bargaining Power

of Buyers

Source: M. E. Porter, Competitive Strategy: Techniques for Analyzing Industries and Competitors 187

(1980).

Many of the elements of the five forces approach have been known to or used in

economics for a long time. Also, many of the considerations raised in the five forces

model appear somewhere in current merger analysis.

Five forces analysis is different in

how, when and why the model is applied. Current antitrust analysis first determines the

relevant geographic and product market, then uses its tools to analyze competitive effects.

Current analysis starts with seller concentration as the principal metric. Other

considerations are brought in, both only later and secondarily. Five forces analysis, on

the other hand, avoids the first step by going straight to analyzing competitive effects in

any and all submarkets deemed relevant by customers and competitors. It views seller

concentration as only one and not the most important determinant of rivalry.

It brings in

all five forces as equally important. Finally, it does not rely heavily on price and quantity

as the principal indicators of welfare.

By assessing competition beyond existing rivals, the need is reduced for debates on

where to draw industry boundaries, or the relevant market in antitrust terms. Any

definition of a market is essentially a choice of where to draw the line between

established competitors and substitute products, between existing firms and potential

entrants, and between existing firms and suppliers and buyers. If these influences on

competition are all recognized, and their relative impact assessed, as they are in five

forces analysis, then where the lines are actually drawn becomes more or less irrelevant

to strategy formulation and, I suggest, the antitrust analysis of competition. Latent

sources of competition will not be overlooked, nor will key dimensions of competition.

The need to determine the relevant market is eliminated.

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 16

While there is a systematic approach to market definition defined in the Merger

Guidelines, it begins with the questionable premise that a single market definition is a

meaningful concept. Moreover, the approach to market definition relies heavily on price

effects which are an incomplete measure of social benefit, not to mention a largely shortterm

and static one.

Productivity Growth and Forms of Competition. The multidimensional nature of

rivalry is important for understanding the link between rivalry and productivity.

Some

forms of rivalry are more productivity-enhancing than others, and thus are more valued

socially.

For example, one can array types of rivalry along a spectrum including the following

(see also figure 7):

1. Competition based on imitation / price discounting

2. Competition based on strategic positioning.

The first type of competition is on operational effectiveness, or the extent to which

companies approach best practices in areas such as production processes, technologies,

marketing methods, and management techniques. The second, and more fundamental to

success in an advanced economy, is competition to create different value propositions for

customers, a function of the degree to which companies have distinctive strategies.

Figure 7 Rivalry and Productivity Growth

Imitation and Price

Discounting

Strategic

Rivalry

o Homogeneous products / services

at low prices

o Multiple, different value

propositions

– e. g.

, features, services,

processes, price levels

o Different approaches to design,

operations, marketing, etc.

“Zero sum competition”Positive sum competition”

o Incremental cost improvements o Potential for fundamental process

improvements

o Lots of customer choice

o Expanded market

o Little true customer choice

o Imitate best practices

Assessing the two according to the productivity growth standard gives very different

results. Imitation-based competition leads to similar products among rivals and strong

pressures for price discounting. Strategic competition occurs when rivals pursue different

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 17

value propositions: some firms offer low prices producing stripped down products, others

have higher prices but provide better service, while still others concentrate on various

segments of the market, tailoring their products and value chains accordingly.

If price / cost margins are used as the metric of social benefit, then imitation and price

discounting seem ideal.

Customers get the benefit of low prices, and the ability to play

one company against others. From a productivity growth standpoint, however, this form

of competition may lead to slower dynamic improvement. Competition on strategic

positioning can foster increased variety and greater choices for customers in terms of the

product that best meets their needs, not to mention more innovation in products and

processes. In strategic competition, markets often expand as new needs are met and new

customers are drawn into the market. It is important to note that internationally

competitive, advanced nations have more innovation- and differentiation-based

competition, while less competitive nations tend to compete on imitation and price. 19

This analysis leads to the controversial conclusion that holding down profitability is

the wrong issue for society.

Profitability has a contingent relationship with productivity

growth. The American software industry is far more profitable than the software

industries in other countries, but it is also far more productive and internationally

competitive. High profits are fine, provided competition is healthy and there are strong

pressures for dynamic improvement. The productivity growth standard, then, casts new

light on how we assess competition. It reveals the importance of understanding the kind

of competition a nation should really be looking for.

III.

2. 2. Measuring the health of local competition: The Diamond framework

As has been argued, it is not sufficient to consider only industry competition

generally. We must also have a means of gauging the health of local competition.

Here,

one such approach to assessing the potential productivity of a local business environment

is embodied in the so-called diamond framework. 20

The productivity of a national business environment can be modeled using four

interacting components that can be depicted as a diamond (see figure 8). These are:

1. Context for firm strategy and rivalry

2. Factor (input) conditions

3. Demand conditions

19 For supporting statistical findings, see Porter, supra note 5.

Results are similar in previous years’

reports. See the full The Global Competitiveness Reports for 1998, 1999 & 2000; and Porter, Takeuchi

& Sakakibara, supra note 7.

20 M. E. Porter, The Competitive Advantage of Nations (1990). For the empirical application of Diamond

theory to 59 countries, see The Global Competitiveness Report 2000, at 40-58, 101-221, including data

definitions and sources at 223-333.

For 1998 and 1999, see The Global Competitiveness Report for

those years. For an extensive empirical application of Diamond theory to Japan, see Porter, Takeuchi

& Sakakibara, supra note 7.

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 18

4. Related and supporting industries

Like the five forces, this framework aims to capture the many influences on the

productivity of the local business environment in an industry or overall.

Rivalry among

locally based competitors is not only important to productivity growth directly but also

creates positive externalities for the local business environment. A group of competing

local rivals helps customers become more knowledgeable and competitive, encourages

more specialized suppliers to develop, and enhances the local supply of high-quality,

specialized inputs. This gives rise to a series of new questions that must be addressed in

analyzing the impact on competition of a merger or other competitive practice, which will

be discussed below.

Figure 8 The Externalities of Rivalry: Locational Determinants of Productivity

and Productivity Growth

Related and

Supporting

Industries

Related and

Supporting

Industries

o Open and vigorous competition

among locally based rivals

o Rivalry among locally-based competitors is not only important directly but also creates positive

externalities for the local business environment

Context for

Firm

Strategy

and Rivalry

Context for

Firm

Strategy

and Rivalry

Factor

(Input)

Conditions

Factor

(Input)

Conditions

o Sophisticated and demanding

local customer (s) whose needs

anticipate those elsewhere

o Unusual local demand in

specialized segments that can be

served globally

o Presence of capable, locally based

suppliers and firms in related fields

Demand

Conditions

Demand

Conditions

o A local context that encourages

investment and sustained upgrading

o Availability of high quality

and specialized

inputs

Source: M. E. Porter, The Competitive Advantage of Nations 133 (1990).

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 19

IV. EVALUATING MERGERS AND JOINT VENTURES

IV. 1. Why mergers should be of particular concern for antitrust

Where productivity growth is the central goal of antitrust, it becomes clear that

mergers should be treated with special caution compared to other corporate growth

strategies. This is true for five reasons:

First, mergers raise almost inevitable issues for the health of competition by removing

independent competitors from the market. The question is not whether there is a risk to

competition, but how much.

This risk stems from the potential lessening of competitive

pressure among firms in the industry, the potential reduction in product choice and

variety, and the reduction in the number of different approaches being pursued to

product / process development and hence the likelihood of innovation.

Second, a merger requires no “skill, foresight, and industry,” 21 only financial

resources. It demands no new strategy, and yields no automatic productivity

improvements. By contrast, introducing a new product, changing a distribution model, or

building a new plant are far more likely to boost productivity. Society, then, should be

biased in favor of independent company actions over mergers.

Third, the empirical evidence is striking that mergers have a low success rate.

A wide

range of studies finds that most mergers do not meet expectations, and most of the profits

are captured by the seller, not the buyer.

Fourth, the strategy literature suggests that smaller, focused acquisitions are more

likely to improve productivity than mergers among leaders. When a large company buys

a small company and integrates it into its strategy, major productivity gains are possible.

Mergers among large companies appear to rarely yield such benefits, though they may

produce reduction in joint overhead and eliminate major competitors from a market.

Fifth, there are strong financial market pressures favoring mergers over other growth

strategies. These arise at least in part from agency problems afflicting both investment

managers compensated based on near term stock price appreciation, and company

executives given incentives with stock options.

Finally, accounting rules make merger a vehicle for distorted performance

measurement, creating artificial pressures for companies to merge.

We cannot assume that a merger will be efficient and profitable just because

companies propose it. Companies make mistakes. Every merger needs to be weighed

against the productivity growth standard.

Indeed, a positive antitrust policy based on

21 U. S. v. Aluminum Co. of America, 148 F. 2 d 416, 430 (2 d Cir.

1945) (Hand, J. ).

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 20

productivity growth might actually enhance both the performance of companies and

consumer welfare, which would be even better for society.

IV. 2. Towards a New Merger Evaluation Process

In dealing with a proposed merger, the primary concern for antitrust should be how

the merger, if allowed, would affect productivity growth.

We must consider both likely

future productivity growth in the industry, as well as the near term productivity impact on

the merged firms. The effect of the merger on the health of competition will be central to

its likely productivity impact, net of any direct positive productivity growth impacts that

can be convincingly demonstrated.

Three Levels of Analysis. In analyzing a merger or joint venture then, the three basic

levels of analysis needed are:

1.

Merger significance and baseline productivity growth analysis.

2. The effect of the transaction on the health of competition using the five forces

and the diamond framework in all significant markets and submarkets that are

relevant based on industry and customer practice.

3. A risk / reward analysis of the merger, where its effect on the health of

competition is weighed against proposed direct benefits using the productivity

growth standard.

IV.

2. 1. Significance and Baseline Productivity Growth Analysis

This analysis can be broken up into three principal tasks: (1) identifying the set of

relevant markets and submarkets and the relevant geographic area; (2) determining

whether or not the firm meets a predetermined combined market share cutoff in the

relevant markets and submarkets; and if so, (3) establishing the baseline productivity

performance of the industry and the firms party to the transaction.

Step 1. Rather than going through the lengthy and controversial exercise of trying to

define the market affected by a merger, this new merger evaluation process is applied to

all relevant markets and submarkets.

There are usually a number of economically

relevant market definitions, and each of these is considered. In determining plausible

markets or submarkets, three practical criteria can be helpful:

1. How the industry itself defines submarkets

2. How consumers segment the market

3.

Whether there is a competitor focused on the submarket (i. e. , a focused

company dedicated only to serving the submarket, which suggests that it is a

viable array of products, varieties, and customers with distinct needs)

DRAFT VERSION: 07/22/02

Page 21

Once all plausible markets and submarkets have been identified, the geographic area

over which local externalities apply is determined. Note that the relevant geographic area

is not based on the geography of sales, but on the externalities in production. The starting

assumption is that the geographic unit is the national economy.

In some industries, the

relevant geographic area can be smaller than a nation. Clusters occur within a region or

metropolitan area. In some cases, externalities can cross national borders of immediate

neighboring countries.

Step 2. To invest the resources required to investigate a particular merger or joint

venture, some significance threshold is inevitable.

We advocate a relatively low

minimum market share threshold of, say, 25 percent combined share in any submarket

(discussed below). Such a threshold will conserve resources and screen out transactions

where the probability of material impact on competition is small.

There is no contradiction between this cut-off level and our rejection of seller

concentration as a measure of market power. We use concentration solely as a

significance indicator. A merger involving a small portion of any submarket is unlikely

to raise important a.